A fundamental building block of economic theory is the fact that increasing (or decreasing) the price of a commodity reduces (or increases) demand for that commodity. Price elasticity of demand refers to the extent to which use of a product falls or rises after increases or decreases in its price. If price elasticity of demand for a product were very low–that is, if it were inelastic–then demand would fall or rise only slightly in response to price changes. For instance, if price elasticity for a particular good were about –0.1, then demand for that good would fall by only 0.1% for every 1% increase in price. Demand would fall by 1% for a 10% increase in price, by 2% for a 20% price increase and so on. Demand for a good with high price elasticity would fall much more sharply in response to price increases. If price elasticity of demand for a good were about –1.0, then demand for that good would fall by 1% for every 1% increase in price. Demand would fall by 10% for a 10% price increase, 20% for a 20% price increase, 100% for a 100% price increase, and so on.
While demand for tobacco products is not as elastic as demand for many other consumer products1 research has consistently demonstrated that increases in the price of tobacco products are followed by moderate falls in both the percentage of people smoking and the amount or number of tobacco products that remaining smokers consume.2,3 The percentage of people smoking declines because tax increases discourage non-users from starting, encourage current users to quit and, also very important, discourage former smokers from starting again.3 Because increases in tobacco taxes result in higher tobacco prices for everyone, the effect of even small resulting reductions in tobacco use can be very large across the whole population.
13.1.1 Estimates of elasticity
Why people reduce smoking in response to increases in the price of tobacco products has been a matter of some conjecture–see Section 13.1.6. However there is no doubt that they do. The extent to which demand for tobacco products responds to changes in price is an empirical question, the answer to which can be ascertained by measuring trends in consumption as prices and other relevant factors change.
Depending on the size of the price increase, reduced consumption of tobacco products following increases in tobacco taxes can be quite substantial. In 1999, a World Bank review concluded that, all else being equal, price rises of about 10% would on average reduce tobacco consumption by about 4% in developed countries and about 8% in developing countries.4, 5 In their 2003 meta-analysis reviewing 86 studies published to the year 2001 which examined the price elasticity of demand for tobacco products, Gallet and List6 found a mean price elasticity of –0.48, meaning that, on average, a 10% increase in price will be followed by a decrease in consumption of 4.8%.
The review conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer published in 2011 concluded that studies on the impact of price increases on aggregate demand in high income countries on average find price elasticity of about–0.4, with most estimates from the US and UK falling in a relatively narrow range between–0.2 and –0.6.7
13.1.2 Various methods of measuring elasticity
Price elasticity can be calculated in many different ways, and various methods have different advantages and different problems (see Section 13.1.7).
Many studies examining the price elasticity of demand have used aggregate data–that is, data at a country or state level on the total amount of tobacco purchased or taxed for the entire population. Some of these studies have analysed changes in taxable or reported sales of all tobacco products, and some have looked at cigarettes alone. Some have measured the weight of product sold, others the number of units. Some studies have compared consumption in the same jurisdiction with different prices over time (time-series analyses). Others have compared consumption in jurisdictions with different prices at the same points in time (cross-sectional studies).
Other studies make use of surveys conducted regularly among school students, adults or households. These might be surveys that ask about smoking habits or they might be surveys about spending on a whole range of household items. A small number of studies have looked at consumption as reported by a panel of smokers interviewed (about their consumption and various factors which might affect it) before and after tax increases over time. In recent times, behavioural economists have examined the response of individuals not to real-life price increases, but rather to price increases simulated in behavioural experiments in laboratories.
Researchers have also used a variety of statistical models for specifying demand and for estimating elasticity.
In their comprehensive review, Gallet and List6 found that resulting estimates of price elasticity from all these sorts of studies were generally fairly similar and did not differ systematically depending on the design or method of analysis used. Studies that measured responses to price changes in the short term tended to report lower elasticity than studies that reported long-run estimates (–0.40 compared with –0.44). Studies published more recently and in high-quality journals also tend to report slightly lower estimates, reflecting increasing sophistication in modelling and the greater number of factors also affecting consumption being taken into account in more recent research.6
13.1.3 Impact of price increases on uptake, continued consumption and quitting
Data from surveys of individuals across a population allow researchers to examine in more detail the impact of price increases on both smoking participation (that is, whether people smoke at all) and smoking intensity (that is, how much people smoke). Different studies have drawn differing conclusions about the relative contribution of declines in prevalence and declines in smoking intensity.8
Overall, recent research among adults indicates that roughly half of the impact of price on tobacco consumption results from reductions in prevalence, and roughly half results from remaining smokers smoking less frequently.8 Higher prices increase prevalence by increasing interest in quitting, quit attempts and successful cessation.8 Higher prices can reduce consumption among remaining smokers by reducing consumption by daily smokers.8 Recent studies also show that prices can reduce consumption by increasing the likelihood that smokers will smoke only on some days.8
Unlike for adults where prices affect both participation and intensity, early researchers assumed that most of the effects of price on young people smoking were on participation, mostly by reducing smoking initiation. Studies examining the relative effects of price on participation and smoking intensity among youth have reached varying conclusions,9,10 but those that have used the longest panels of data11, 12 have generally been able to detect some effect on both initiation and quitting.13 The review of the literature conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer3 concluded the following
- Cigarette prices influence different stages of uptake of cigarette use, with a relatively larger impact at later stages.
- Most but not all longitudinal studies from high-income countries find that smoking initiation is inversely related to price.
- As cigarette prices increases, smoking cessation among young people increases.
- Price has a direct effect on young people, and also an indirect effect through both peer and family influence.9
13.1.4 Price sensitivity among various population groups
Studies collecting data from individuals also allow researchers to assess how different population groups tend to respond to changes in price.14
Since young adults more commonly than older adults are occasional rather than regular smokers, it is theoretically possible that they may be less influenced by price changes. However, teenage and younger smokers generally earn lower wages and are less dependent on tobacco, both of which would tend to make them more price sensitive.15 Early cigarette demand studies by Lewit and colleagues using individual-level data16,17 found a strong inverse relationship between price sensitivity and age, with younger smokers reducing consumption much more than adults in response to the same price increases. This finding was thrown into doubt by an influential Rand study by Wasserman and colleagues in 1991.18 More recent studies however11,12,19,20 supported earlier conclusions of Lewit and colleagues that younger smokers tend to be more price sensitive.
In the US Surgeon General's review of the literature published in 1994,21 estimates of elasticity of youth cigarette demand ranged from –0.9 to –1.5 (about three times the level of elasticity of adult cigarette demand). Across all the studies published up until 2001, Gallet and List also found greater responsiveness among younger people, with an average price elasticity of –1.43 for teenagers, –0.76 for young adults, and –0.32 for adults.6
The most recent review of literature on the effect of prices on youth smoking conducted by the International Agency for Research on Cancer9 concluded that price elasticity of demand for teenagers was somewhere between –0.5 and –1.2%.9
Studies have differed as to findings about the relative price sensitivity of women compared with that of men. Townsend and colleagues (1994) found that women in the late 1980s and early 1990s in Britain were more sensitive than men to increases in tobacco prices. Chaloupka and Pacula,22 however, found that the prevalence elasticity for young American men was almost twice as large as that for young women. Across all the studies published until 2001, Gallet and List6 found an average price sensitivity of –0.50 for men, and –0.34 for women. More recent studies have generally failed to find gender differences in price sensitivity.8
Studies in high-income counties have also tended to show greater price sensitivity among lower socio-economic groups.23 Low-income groups were more responsive to increases in cigarette prices in the UK in the 1980s and early 1990s.24,25,26 In the US, smoking rates of young black men are significantly more responsive to changes in price than are smoking rates among young white men.27
While not every study has reached the same conclusion–different levels of access to cheaper tobacco products over time and in different countries may explain some of the inconsistent findings28–the majority of studies in high-income countries have found greater price sensitivity among those on lower incomes.23,28 See Section 13.11 for further details.
Smokers in poorer nations also tend to be more sensitive to price, with estimates of price sensitivity generally around 0.8% , about double that in more affluent countries.29 Blecher and Walbeek conclude, however, that when changes in affordability rather than changes in price are taken into account, the level of sensitivity in developing countries may be similar to that observed in developed countries.30
13.1.5 Price elasticity for tobacco products other than cigarettes
US,31 Canadian32 and Finnish33 research has concluded that an increase in the price of manufactured cigarettes can lead to an increase in sales of hand-rolled cigarettes and other tobacco products. Increases in the price of those products without simultaneous increases in the price of cigarettes are also followed by drops in consumption.33
In Australia, use of roll-your-own tobacco has increased in recent years following substantial increases in tax levels on all tobacco products (see Section 2.5). Increases in use of roll-your-own have been even more pronounced in countries where taxes on loose tobacco have not kept pace with taxes on cigarettes.34
13.1.6 Theories of demand
Because many people are highly dependent on tobacco-delivered nicotine and persist in smoking despite recognising that tobacco products are dangerous, many early economists theorised that tobacco use was an irrational behaviour and not suitable for conventional economic analysis.35 Other economists simply ignored the addictive nature of tobacco products. More recent studies explicitly address the addictive nature of cigarette smoking. The economic models of addiction underlying such research can be divided into three groups:13 imperfectly rational models of addictive behaviour; models of myopic addictive behaviour; and models of rational addictive behaviour.
Imperfectly rational addiction models assume that the rational, far-sighted part of a person wants good health and a long life but that their efforts to quit are repeatedly undone by the 'wayward' part of their personality that quite simply 'adores' smoking. Proponents of imperfectly rational addiction models hypothesise that consumption will fall sharply in response to price increases, but will then drift back again with time.
The myopic addiction model assumes that addicted smokers are short-sighted. Myopic addiction theorists predict that factors such as price and income will affect uptake of smoking but that once addicted patterns of consumption are well established, individuals tend to ignore or discount future costs (both monetary and health related). They hypothesise that, while decreases in price will increase consumption and increases in price will reduce consumption, the effect of price increases will be much smaller than the effect of any price decreases.
The rational addiction model by contrast rejects the proposition that smokers behave myopically. It asserts that even addicted individuals do take into account future costs. The model assumes that addicted smokers make a rational choice, weighing up the pleasure of current smoking and the unpleasantness of withdrawal that comes with quitting on the one hand and the cost of current and continued smoking and the long-term health effects on the other. Different people will make different decisions depending on how much they value good health, how unpleasant they believe it will be to quit, and how much financial pressure they are under. Individuals also differ in the extent to which they prefer short-term over long-term benefits. Nevertheless, the choice an individual makes will take all relevant factors into account and be a rational one. Proponents of the rational addiction model such as Becker and Murphy36 have demonstrated that current consumption of an addictive good tends to be inversely related not only to the current price of the good but also to the past and predicted future prices.37, 38 The model also suggests that more-educated and older people will be responsive to both new information and to price increases, and that less-educated and younger people will be much less responsive to information about long-term effects and relatively more responsive to immediate changes in price.
The rational addiction model was popular among many theorists and researchers over the late 1980s and the 1990s, but recently has been criticised on several grounds. First, it implies that individuals have good foresight: a very accurate picture of what the future is going to be like. In reality however, it is evident that some people give little thought to the future. While they may be able to recite some of the diseases caused by smoking, they do not fully appreciate the nature and extent of health risks and may not be able to accurately envisage what their life would be like if they became very ill or disabled due to smoking. Second, the model would predict that individuals rarely regret past decisions about consumption, a theory not borne out in interviews with current smokers, almost all of whom regret ever having started smoking.39 Third, critics argue that it might be that smokers do not actually choose future consumption. Rather, by continuing to smoke they are choosing only current consumption: future consumption happens to them rather than being chosen by them.
13.1.7 Limitations of studies assessing price sensitivity
There is no doubt that smokers are responsive to changes in the price of tobacco products. However there is no one definitive way of quantifying price sensitivity. Studies that use individual-level data and those that use aggregate data are both subject to various limitations.
The reliability of individual-level data is very much dependent on adequate sampling and recall and honesty by respondents about factors such as purchase of illicit tobacco products. Under-reporting of numbers of cigarettes (or amount of other tobacco products) smoked is also a significant problem.40 Using aggregate data on taxable product sales avoids these problems and ensures that researchers are looking at the impact of price changes on the entire market; however, studies that use such data are subject to a number of different limitations.
First, without asking a representative sample of consumers about the prices of the products they are able to buy over time, it is sometimes difficult to determine exactly what the average or typical price increase is (see Section 13.3.2). Manufacturers use a variety of methods of cushioning consumers from the effect of the increases in taxes. It is by no means straightforward to assess the extent of price increases across a market where retailers engage in various degrees of discounting, 'specialling' and bulk-selling and where tax-free and illicit tobacco products are available.
Specifying changing quantities of tobacco products is similarly not straightforward. Studies that measure the weight of product may not sufficiently account for tobacco companies gradually reducing the taxable weight of cigarettes (without corresponding decreases in delivery of toxins).41 Studies that analyse changes in the number of products generally do not take into account any consumer shift to possibly more toxic tobacco products.42
Finally, studies often do not adequately take into account all the less-easily-measured factors that affect tobacco consumption, such as negative (unpaid) publicity about tobacco in the media and anti-smoking sentiment in the community. Often changes in such factors coincide with or precede tax increases, and the effects of such factors may multiply rather than simply add to the effect of price increases.
Concluding note
Despite debates on the finer points of theory and despite all these methodological limitations, there is no doubt that price exerts a profound impact on tobacco consumption.3 Falls in consumption following large price increases are consistently much more rapid and more significant than falls following implementation of most other tobacco-control policies, and the World Bank has stated that increasing tobacco taxes is the single most effective measure that governments can take to reduce health burdens.2 Increasing taxes on tobacco is a key plank in every major international tobacco-control strategy. 2,43–49
Relevant news and research
For recent news items and research on this topic, click here.( Last updated October 2024)
References
1. Tennant RB. The American cigarette industry: a study in economic analysis and public policy. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1950.
2. World Bank. Curbing the epidemic: governments and the economics of tobacco control. Washington: World Bank, 1999. Available from: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/1999/05/437174/curbing-epidemic-governments-economics-tobacco-control
3. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Handbooks of Cancer Prevention, Vol.14. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/
4. Jha P. Avoidable global cancer deaths and total deaths from smoking. Nature Reviews. Cancer 2009;9(9):655–64. Available from: http://www.nature.com/nrc/journal/v9/n9/full/nrc2703.html
5. Jha P and Chaloupka F, eds. Tobacco Control in Developing Countries. Oxford University Press on behalf of The Human Development Network, the World Bank, and The Economics Advisory Service, World Health Organization, 2000.
6. Gallet C and List J. Cigarette demand: a meta-analysis of elasticities. Health Economics 2003;12(10):821–35. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/journal/101520325/abstract?CRETRY=1&SRETRY=0
7. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 4. Tax, price and aggregate demand for tobacco products. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/
8. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 5. Tax, price and adult tobacco use. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/
9. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 6. Tax, price and tobacco use among young people. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/
10. DeCicca P, Kenkel D, Mathios A, Shin YJ and Lim JY. Youth smoking, cigarette prices, and anti-smoking sentiment. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2006. Available from: http://www.nber.org/papers/w12458
11. Evans WN and Huang LX. Cigarette taxes and teen smoking: new evidence from panels of repeated cross-sections. Department of Economics Working Paper: University of Maryland, 1998.
12. Tauras J and Chaloupka F. Price, clean indoor air laws, and cigarette smoking: evidence from longitudinal data for young adults. NBER Working paper no. 6937. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1999. Available from: http://tigger.uic.edu/~fjc/
13. Chaloupka FJ and Warner KE. The economics of smoking. In: Newhouse, J and Cuyler, A, eds. The handbook of health economics. New York: Elsevier Science, 2000. 1539-627. Available from: http://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeheachp/1-29.htm
14. Farrelly M and Bray J. Response to increases in cigarette prices by race/ethnicity, income, and age groups–United States, 1976-1993. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report 1998;47(29):605-9. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/00054047.htm
15. Ding A. Youth are more sensitive to price changes in cigarettes than adults. The Yale Journal of Biology and Medicine 2003;76(3):115–24. Available from: http://www.ingentaconnect.com/content/yjbm/jobm/2003/00000076/00000003/art00004
16. Lewit EM and Coate D. The potential for using excise taxes to reduce smoking. Journal of Health Economics 1982;1(2):121–45. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B6V8K-45BC6NV-B&_user=10&_coverDate=08%2F31%2F1982&_rdoc=2&_fmt=summary&_orig=browse&_srch=doc-info(%23toc%235873%231982%23999989997%23289738%23FLP%23display%23Volume)&_cdi=5873&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_ct=7&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=f61b82f985ad0bd335c236dc281b4ab6
17. Lewit EM, Coate D and Grossman M. The effects of government regulation on teenage smoking. The Journal of Law & Economics 1981;24(3):545–69. Available from: http://www.jstor.org/pss/725277
18. Wasserman J, Manning W, Newhouse J and Winkler J. The effects of excise taxes and regulations on cigarette smoking. Journal of Health Economics 1991;101(1):43-64. Available from: http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_udi=B6V8K-458XP03-4&_user=10&_coverDate=05%2F31%2F1991&_rdoc=4&_fmt=summary&_orig=browse&_srch=doc-info(%23toc%235873%231991%23999899998%23288487%23FLP%23display%23Volume)&_cdi=5873&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_ct=8&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=1fe195cce4937f547e0c24ec77f5e3fb
19. Lewit E, Hyland A, Kerrebrock N and Cummings K. Price, public policy, and smoking in young people. Tobacco Control 1997;6(suppl. 2):S17–24. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/citation/6/suppl_2/S17
20. Chaloupka FJ and Grossman M. Price, Tobacco Control Policies and Youth Smoking. Working Paper no. 5740. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996. Available from: http://tigger.uic.edu/~fjc/
21. US Department of Health and Human Services. Preventing tobacco use among young people. A report of the Surgeon General, 1994. Atlanta, Georgia: Public Health Service, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Office on Smoking and Health, 1994. Available from: http://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/data_statistics/sgr/sgr_1994/index.htm
22. Chaloupka FJ and Pacula RL. Sex and race differences in young people's responsiveness to price and tobacco control policies. Tobacco Control 1999;8(4):373-7. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/abstract/8/4/373
23. Thomas S, Fayter D, Misso K, Ogilvie D, Petticrew M, Sowden A, et al. Population tobacco control interventions and their effects on social inequalities in smoking: systematic review. Tobacco Control 2008;17(4):230–7. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/content/abstract/17/4/230
24. Townsend JL. Cigarette tax, economic welfare and social class patterns of smoking. Applied Economics 1987;19:355-65. Available from: http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00036848700000007#preview
25. Townsend JL, Roderick P and Cooper J. Cigarette smoking by socioeconomic group, sex, and age: effects of price, income, and health publicity. British Medical Journal 1994;309(6959):923–6. Available from: http://www.bmj.com/cgi/content/full/309/6959/923
26. Townsend J. Price and consumption of tobacco. British Medical Bulletin 1996;52(1):132–42. Available from: http://bmb.oxfordjournals.org/cgi/content/abstract/52/1/132
27. Chaloupka FJ and Wechsler H. Price, tobacco control policies and smoking among young adults. Journal of Health Economics 1997;16(3):359-73. Available from: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=225791
28. International Agency for Research on Cancer. Chapter 7. Tax, price and tobacco use among the poor. Effectiveness of tax and price policies for tobacco control. Lyon, France: IARC, 2011. Available from: http://www.iarc.fr/en/publications/list/handbooks/
29. Lance P, Akin J, Dow W and Loh C. Is cigarette smoking in poorer nations highly sensitive to price? Evidence from Russia and China. Journal of Health Economics 2004;23(1):173–89. Available from: http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/15154693
30. Blecher EH and van Walbeek CP. An international analysis of cigarette affordability. Tobacco Control 2004;13(4):339-46. Available from: http://tc.bmjjournals.com/cgi/content/abstract/13/4/339
31. Ohsfeldt R, Boyle R and Capilouto E. Effects of tobacco excise taxes on the use of smokeless tobacco products in the USA. Health Economics 1997;6(5):525–32. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/abstract/14681/ABSTRACT
32. Thomson N and McLeod I. The effects of economic variables upon the demand for cigarettes in Canada. Mathematical Scientist 1976;1:121–31.
33. Pekurinen M. The demand for tobacco products in Finland. British Journal of Addiction 1989;84(10):1183–92. Available from: http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/journal/119445417/abstract?CRETRY=1&SRETRY=0
34. Sukin K. Tobacco smokescreen. The Nation.2006. Available from: http://www.nationmultimedia.com/2006/01/22/headlines/index.php?news=headlines_19718718.html
35. Elster J. Ulysses and the Sirens: studies in rationality and irrationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979.
36. Becker G and Murphy K. A theory of rational addiction. The Journal of Political Economy 1988;96(4):675–700. Available from: http://www.drugtext.org/library/articles/becker02.htm
37. Becker G, Grossman M and Murphy K. Rational addiction and the effect of price on consumption. The American Economic Review 1991;82(2):237–41. Available from: http://www.drugtext.org/library/articles/becker1.htm
38. Becker G, Grossman M and Murphy K. An empirical analysis of cigarette addiction. The American Economic Review 1994;84(3):396–418. Available from: www.soc.washington.edu/users/matsueda/Becker%20AER.pdf
39. Fong G, Hammond D, Laux F, Zanna M, Cummings K, Borland R, et al. The near-universal experience of regret among smokers in four countries: findings from the International Tobacco Control Policy Evaluation Survey. Nicotine & Tobacco Research 2004;6(suppl. 3):S341–51. Available from: http://www.informaworld.com/smpp/content~content=a753998174~db=all~order=page
40. Warner K. Possible increase in the underreporting of cigarette consumption. Journal of the American Statistical Association 1978;73(362):314-18.
41. Chapman S. Changes in adult cigarette consumption per head in 128 countries 1986-90. Tobacco Control 1992;1:281-4. Available from: http://tobaccocontrol.bmj.com/cgi/reprint/1/4/281
42. Evans WN and Farrelly MC. The compensating behaviour of smokers: taxes, tar and nicotine. Department of Economics Working Paper. University of Maryland, 1995.
43. Gray N and Daube M. Guidelines for smoking control. UICC technical report series no. 52. Geneva: International Union Against Cancer, 1980.
44. World Health Organization. Tools for advancing tobacco control in the XX1st century: policy recommendations for smoking cessation and treatment of tobacco dependence. Tools for public health. Geneva: WHO, 2003. Available from: http://www.wpro.who.int/NR/rdonlyres/8D25E4D3-BB81-479E-8DF5-7BAF674DB104/0/PolicyRecommendations.pdf
45. World Health Organization. Higher taxes key to battle against tobacco use, says new WHO/World Bank publication. 2000. Available from: http://www.who.int/inf-pr-2000/en/pr2000-53.html
46. Jamrozik K. Policy priorities for tobacco control. British Medical Journal 2004;328(7446):1007-9. Available from: PM:15105328
47. Ministerial Council on Drug Strategy. Australian National Tobacco Strategy 2004-2009. Canberra: Department of Health and Ageing, 2005. Available from: http://www.health.gov.au/internet/main/publishing.nsf/Content/tobacco-strat
48. World Health Organization. MPOWER: A policy package to reverse the tobacco epidemic. Geneva: World Health Organization, 2008. Available from: http://www.who.int/tobacco/mpower/mpower_english.pdf
49. Australian Government. Taking preventative action: Government's response to Australia: the healthiest country by 2020. Canberra: Department of Health and Ageing, 2010. Available from: http://yourhealth.gov.au/internet/yourhealth/publishing.nsf/Content/report-preventativehealthcare